The business
landscape in Europe is on the verge of significant changes, which may affect
the future of many industries and the long-term prospects of the EU economy.
It is well known
that Europe did not manage to have the same number of successful start-ups as
the United States or some countries in Asia do and the size of the EU behemoths,
compared to competitors in other parts of the world, is actually shrinking, as
well as the number of European giants in the world economy landscape.. There are several reasons for the situation,
from red tape and bad public policies, to an ageing population in several
countries and a failure to realize that the current welfare enjoyed by most
Europeans in inherited from the previous generations, which, in their turn,
have been more dynamic and better motivated than today.
Europe
industries are mostly legacy business, designed and developed in a different
economic context. When the conditions
change and getting profits becomes more difficult, these industries should seek
to reinvent, up to making real revolutions in their respective businesses.
Instead they
pursue another strategy, which belongs rather to the 19th century than to the
present times: consolidation, by way of acquisitions and mergers. Getting larger certainly brings short and
medium term benefits, through increased economies of scale and larger
portfolios of brands and customers (as customers use to follow the brands they
like).
But this is no
guarantee for more innovation; better products or services and the benefits to
the markets and the consumers, on the short, medium and long run are highly questionable.
The frenzy of consolidation by undertakings in industries which went well
through the economic crisis but now seek to rule the market by sheer size is definitely
driven mainly by the intention to maintain status quo (and, hence, to avoid
radical changes in their business models) and by pressure coming from
shareholders to keep revenues and profits up in markets where the purchasing
power has been eroded drastically by the economic crisis.
In order to
illustrate this trend, I would take two examples of mergers, agreed recently
and which face the scrutiny of the European Commission, acting as a competition
agency (the two merges also demonstrate why prior merger control is good). Interestingly enough, the two mergers are
proposed in industries, which are in a vertical relationship, which means that
the European Commission should analyse their horizontal effects in correlation
to the effects occurring at the other levels of the chain. Due to the close market relationship of the
participants, the European Commission should analyse the two mergers in
conjunction with each other.
It is about the
merger between Rexam and Ball and the announced deal between Anheuser-Busch
InBev and SAB Miller.
In the first
case, Ball, the world leader of the market for production of aluminium cans,
used mainly for beer, soda and energy drinks, attempts to merge with the world
no.2 producer and arch-rival, Rexam.
After years of being head to head and competing fiercely for customers,
the two market leaders decided that they should put their swords at rest and
shake hands.
It is difficult
to guess what made Ball and Rexam decide to go this way, given that the market
in which they operate is rather stable, their position is not yet challenged
seriously by any other competitor and this is unlikely to happen any time soon.
As mentioned in the press release of the European Commission, when the EU
watchdog started the investigation in this matter in July 2015, entering the
production of aluminium cans market is extremely difficult and no disruptive technology
or similar event is in sight, which could change the situation. The financial
crisis cannot be invoked now and the two companies announced healthy results in
the previous years. It looks like two happy companies go together in order to
be even happier.
There are of
course, challenges and the merger could improve the position of the new entity
on its upstream and downstream markets. Negotiations with suppliers – mainly aluminium
producers – and clients could be improved.
Regarding the suppliers, however, the market is not concentrated and
clients such as Rexam and Ball had often the upper hand when it came to the
prices paid for the aluminium. It is
also worth noting that aluminium costs remain always high, due to a variety of
factors, from the difficulty to find aluminium in the Earth crust to the energy
intensive process for extracting the aluminium and making the metal foil
necessary for the cans. This means that
it is highly unlikely that Ball and Rexam will be able to obtain better prices
than those of today.
In the
downstream market, Ball and Rexam are the preferred suppliers of cans almost
anywhere in the European Union – it is sufficient for anyone to just have a
look on the side of the can, when buying a drink in such a packaging (cans
producers always imprint their logo on the side). The beer market itself is
already quite concentrated in most markets in EU and this concentration is
likely to increase, if mergers such as that between AB InBev and SAB Miller
shall be approved by the European Commission. Of course, Ball and Rexam may say
that it is exactly this concentration what justify their merger, in order to be
able to withstand increased bargaining power from their clients. The argument,
however, does not hold ground : in this moment, the bear market has
relatively low levels of concentration, lower anyway than those which will
exist on the aluminium cans market, if the merger would be approved. In this
context – and mergers are analysed primarily taking into account the situation
in the market as it is at the time of the analysis – the new entity will be
able to reap more benefits from the beer, soda and energy drinks producers. The
concentration in the soft drinks markets is even lower than in the beer market
and a giant Ball/Rexam will be able to raise the prices, to its benefit – the
situation might be particularly difficult in the energy drinks market, where
the aluminium can is an essential input – the only packaging used in this
sector.
Looking from a
subjective perspective (that of Ball, Rexam and their shareholders), the merger
between Ball and Rexam is the right thing to do). Seen from a more objective
perspective – the market – the merger does not even promise some benefits, let
alone the risks that this market will become a giant ring in which the new
giant will not be challenged by anyone.
Going to the AB
InBev/SAB Miller proposed merger, things are not any brighter there. Similarly to Ball and Rexam ”marriage” is
difficult to see what benefits consumers might enjoy, as a result of these two
giants creating an even larger giant. Certainly, it is about larger economies
of scale and also economies of scope, in addition to access to new markets by
each of the participants, but since one in three beers produced in the world
will come from the new company, there is highly unlikely that consumers will
get any benefit. Even more
interestingly, the combined brewer would be the happy beneficiary of half of
the profits in this industry.
The effects of
this merger will be different from a region to another and whilst African
markets might benefit of the merger (with new brands entering these markets),
the situation will be very different in Europe, where AB InBev and SAB Miller
are competing fiercely. The two giants
justify that their merger will be able to counter an increase preference of
consumers for crafted beer and for alternative drinks, such as wine. It is however, unclear, how a larger company
will be able to achieve this, given that the switch to locally produced beer
and to wine happens even if often the prices for these products are
higher. In fact, the switch to
alternative products is driven by fashion rather than by price and regards wealthy
(thus, marginal) consumers rather than the typical consumers. If the raise of
competing products would have been the concern, AB InBev and SAB Miller would
seek rather to acquire smaller beer producers or wine producers, which they do
not intend to do now.
We should not
forget that AB InBev has been in a ”shopping” frenzy and has a previous attempt
to acquire the Dutch producer Heineken, in 2014. Last but not least, the merger
has an impressive price tag of approximately 106 billion USD (!), which will
benefit the shareholders of SAB Miller but which will need to be then recovered
from somewhere. AB InBev has a good reputation in cost cutting but even a
genius will find very difficult to cut costs to this extent.
I analysed the
two important mergers in the aluminium cans and beer industry from a static perspective.
But as Carles Esteva Mosso, the Director General for Mergers at the European
Commission put it, on 12 November 2014, at the GCR Annual Conference:
”The most harmful effects are of a dynamic
nature. Indeed, productivity has to be the key driver of sustainable growth
in the EU in the coming years. The beneficial effects of competition for
productivity and innovation are widely recognised: competitive markets create
incentives for firms to increase their internal productivity, that is to become
more efficient in order to stay ahead of rivals; they force less efficient
rivals out of the markets, thus improving the overall industry productivity;
and finally, they also push firms to develop new products and to invest and
innovate.
A concentration that reduces competition may, in
the short term, make life easier for the operators in these markets by allowing
them to raise prices. In the medium and long term, however, these operations
will negatively affect the competitiveness of the whole industry by reducing
incentives to increase efficiency and innovate.
There are plenty of examples of EU-players that have
become world leaders precisely because they faced a very competitive market
structure at home, which incentivised them to increase efficiency and innovate.
The German top-end car manufacturers, BMW, Audi and Mercedes-Benz, with
headquarters separated by only a few hundred kilometres, are one good example
of this.”
Carles Esteva
had two excellent points in his speech:
-
first, that mergers need to be
considered in consideration of markets which are evolving and with particular
attention to how the market may look in the future. Merger analysis is not simple mathematics, it
is about forecast, which means that optimism alone is not sufficient and a sceptical
approach will help in analysing the relevant data.
-
second, that if the European Union needs giants, this
should happen by keeping the competitive pressure at the highest possible
levels. Giants should result from the competitive pressure, not from the
shortcuts offered by the mergers.
This is the
context and these are the criteria based on which the EU competition
authorities should take into account the raise of the giants. Care must be given not to encumber the
competition in the long run and make the consumers pay for the merger.
For instance,
the today mathematics of the two mergers may look out-dated soon, if one of the
smaller competitors of Ball/Rexam and AB InBev/SAB Miller will decide to leave
the market or at least reduce their investments. As long as the gap will widen, as a result of
the mergers, the competitors, who will be the first to feel the heat of the new
giants, might decide to tune down their market activity and refrain from
further investment. Investors in
aluminium cans could switch to other industries where their technology would
assist or to other geographical areas, outside the European Union. Smaller beer
producers might increase their involvement in soft drinks or other alcoholic
drinks, where most of them are already present, such as Carlsberg, which is now
a major producer and bottler of soda drinks. This would mean that the very high market
shares resulting from the concentrations will be even higher in the future and
the respective markets could be ”trapped” a la long in the hands of the giants,
until a disruptive technology will allow for a change.
Thus, Ball/Rexam
and AB InBev/SAB Miller are a test for the European Commission. It is not just about the number of market
players getting from 4 to 3, as it happens in telecoms, where the equations are
complicated by extensive regulation and spectrum scarcity. It is about setting a benchmark, which will
be later used by other industries, which may soon follow the same consolidation
process. In markets which already have
high concentration ratios, when mergers are not pushed from the bottom up by
new and dynamic entrants but from above, by the need to keep the level of the
profits stable, they should not be allowed to go through. The European Commission and other competition
authorities should develop as clear as possible benchmarks, which should give
parties early indication on whether or not the mergers should leave the
boardrooms or not. As indicated by
Carles Esteva Mosso in 2014, the control of economic concentrations is far from
being just a bureaucratic process, where the agencies try to foresee if the
positive effects of the merger will surpass the reduction in competition, which
is always a difficult endeavour (I am speaking as a former competition enforcer
and I am aware that competition authorities have un unpleasant task in
deciding, in advance, whether or not a merger would be detrimental to the
competitive process and to the consumers).
In the end, merger control aims not just at preventing anticompetitive
behaviours but it is also a policy instrument to a larger extent than the
prohibition of anticompetitive agreements and practices (which has been used in
the past for other objectives than the competition).
There are
several industries which are looking with interest what the Commission will do,
the consumers are looking and we, as practitioners acting in the competition
law area, are looking to see if the European Commission will stand to its
reputation of a vigilant watchdog or will prefer to be just optimist and
prefer not to put a stop to consolidation to mergers in industries where
innovation is low and the barriers to entry are high.
Europe needs to
experience a rise of the giants but this should come out of efforts and battles
won over competitors, not from embracing them.